The Origin of the Factory 2

Metals: The Money Factory

One of the first industries to be heavily automated and mechanized was metal production. This was by necessity.

Markets called forth more demand for silver, which called for more production, which called for more production of coins, in a kind of feedback loop.

In South America mines were often high up in the mountains where the air was thinner. That meant that traditional smelting techniques would not work. The Incas, however, has a device known as a guayra, or wind oven. At one point, fifteen thousand of these, produced by Incan craftsmen, were in use by the Spaniards.

To deal with the labor shortage here, the Spanish viceroy adopted the Incan mita system, or corvée labor. Villages were forced to supply labor to the Spanish in place of the Inca rulers. And unlike the Inca, that labor was not involved in things like building, it was used in mining silver ore.

To extract the ore, a new technique was discovered in Mexico. This was the application of mercury to crushed rock in order to more efficiently extract the ore. This required the crushing of massive amounts of rock. To accomplish this on an industrial scale, the Spanish turned to water power:

In order to crush the massive amounts of rock extracted from the giant mountain, the workers used Eurasian technology to build hydraulic wheels and install them at the base of the mountain. Within the first century of mining in Potosí, the workers built 132 such ore-crushing wheels.

To supply energy to turn these wheels in the virtual desert conditions of the high plateau, the Spanish forced thousands of Indians to excavate a series of thirty artificial lakes in the surrounding mountains to capture the small amounts of rain in the area as well as snow that melted and ran off from the higher elevations in the summer. Canals carried the water, which then cascaded down a series of sluices to turn the wheels.

The churning wheels crushed the rock into a fine gravel, and the energy from the waterwheels also powered a series of giant hammers that pounded the gravel into a fine sand the consistency of flour. The “flour” became pasta when the Indians walked on it and mixed it with mercury. IG p. 50

Mechanization did not stop there. The silver was then transported to the Case de Moneda, or house of money. In the past, coins had been struck by using manual dyes and hammer blows by skilled craftsmen on blank slugs of metal. But the massive amounts of silver meant that this hand-production of coins by skilled labor would not suffice. Instead, just like the ore production, waterwheels were pressed into service to automate the striking of vast amounts of silver coins. However, these wheels often ended up being powered by human and animal labor due to the shortage of water:

The innovators of Potosí adapted an indoor version of the waterwheel to supply extra power. Because of the lack of water, men and animals propelled the wheel by trudging in an eternal circle. This closely resembled the threshing mills used in many Old World areas that lacked running water.

The wheels in the mint, however, turned a series of wooden gears up to eight feet in diameter as well as much smaller wheels. When all of the wheels moved in concert, they produced a whopping blow of a hammer much like the hammer used at the base of the mountain to pulverize the ore. Because of the scarcity of wood, craftsmen substituted the more abundant metals for machine parts wherever and whenever practical. IG, p. 51

When the silver was shipped back to Europe, they needed ways to secure the money from pirates, as well as from the people shipping it. To do this, locksmiths devised all sort of new techniques to secure the money in the form of safes and locks.

From extracting the ore and pulverizing it on to minting coins and transporting them, the traditional Old World technology that had sufficed since the days of the ancient Phoenician mines or the mines of Solomon failed to meet the new situation.

The Spanish learned little about metallurgy from the Indians, although in many regards Indian technology was equal to and in some ways superior to European technologies. But the great new magnitude of the mining enterprise in America demanded new techniques in order to produce silver at a rate that the Indians had never before attained.

So much new information about mining developed in these years that in 1640 Barba published his Art of Metals, summarizing this new knowledge and thereby building the foundation for a modern metallurgy that became increasingly important wit the development of industrialization. IG, p. 52

And so, metal provided an example of mechanized mass production. These mechanical techniques using waterwheels will come to play an essential role in the first factories which arrive in other parts of Europe, including the village of Kahl. The Spanish back in Europe tended to not expand this mechanization of industry, because with the silver they could buy whatever they wanted from the rest of Europe. In addition, commerce was seen as unfitting for a noble to engage in, unlike in England. This is why the industrial revolution never took off in Spain. However, the Spanish silver provided a commercial stimulus to the rest of Europe.

Sugar: The First Factories

Sugar cane was not a New World product–it originated in Southeast Asia. It was cultivated widely in India and entered Europe through trading with the Arab world. Sugar is, in fact, an Arabic loan word—sukkar—from the Persian shakar (via the Sanskrit sharkara). Sugar had been introduced into Europe probably during the Crusades. Back then, instead of causing diseases and tooth decay, sugar was considered medicinal. But it very, very rare.

Rather than trade for sugar through the Arab world, it would be useful for Europe to produce its own sugar. But sugar is a tropical plant; like cotton, it does not grow in European soil or temperature conditions.

Before they colonized the New Wold, Europeans occupied and took over the neighboring islands in the Atlantic in a sort of dress rehearsal for the full-scale colonization that was to follow. While England used Ireland for this purpose, the Portuguese settled on the island of Madeira and the Azores and grew sugar there, along with island of São Tomé off the coast of Africa. The Spanish colonized the Canary Islands and planted sugar on Gran Canaria and Tenerife.

When Columbus landed in the Caribbean, he found the ideal spot for growing sugar cane. In fact, sugar was introduced into the Caribbean by Columbus himself from São Tomé on his second voyage (his father-in-law owned a plantation). Before long, the Caribbean became Europe’s sugar daddy:

We all know the appeal of sugar in our candies, cookies, cakes, and coffees, but we’ve lost an appreciation of the critical role it played in the European diet. Sugar did more than furnish calories and sweetness; it make possible storing fruits and vegetables throughout the year.

There were only three ways to keep food before artificial refrigeration: salting it, preserving it, or drying it. Sugar was the essential ingredient for preserves. Before a nineteenth-century German chemist showed how to extract sugar from beets, people had to import it from those tropical areas where sugarcane flourished. Its desirability and rarity did for the islands of the West Indies what oil later did for the Middle East: it gave them a monopoly of a commodity whose demand continued to climb for two centuries.

The Relentless Revolution: A History of Capitalism, p. 63

There a few characteristics about sugar, however, that make it quite different from standard agricultural crops such as wheat, rice, corn or tobacco. For one, the sugar has to be harvested right away, because the sucrose in the cane immediately starts to decay after it is cut. Also, as a tropical plant, it does not grow annually the way cereals do. It takes a year and half from planting to harvesting the crop. That meant that the traditional seasonal timing of agricultural labor disappeared; instead sugar became a year-round crop. Labor on a sugar plantation became divorced from the rhythm of the seasons which had dictated the schedules in agrarian societies, including in Europe.

Also, sugar has to be heavily processed in labor-intensive ways to extract the raw material for granulated sugar—pounding, boiling, etc. The only way all this could work is to centralize everything in a massive operation where everything took place immediately in a sort of assembly line process: harvesting, collecting, boiling, pounding, processing, and shipping.

The only way to really deal with all this is via plantations; no “yeoman farmers” here. Eric Wolf describes the plantation model, while also noting its similarity to military organization:

A plantation can be defined formally as a capital-using unit employing a large labor force under close managerial supervision to produce a crop for sale. The labor force usually works in labor gangs that carry out the repetitive and physically demanding tasks under the watchful eye of foremen who enforce the required sequence and synchronization of tasks.

Plantations tend to be large in size, achieving economies of scale by devoting as much of their resources as possible to the cultivation of a single crop. Large-scale production requires large-scale processing. The bulk product must be moved from the fields to a processing center: the processed crop must be stored until it can be taken to market.

It aim is to produce one or two crops for the markets. That specialization is a source at once of its strength and of its weakness. The organization can respond to increases in market demand; but it is highly vulnerable to economic downturns.

Plantation agriculture therefore takes on something of the order and drill of an army, which led Edgar T. Thompson to characterize it as “military” agriculture.

The combined functions of organizational control, processing and storage create the plantation center, which becomes a post of command, walled off from the surrounding fields and workers’ barracks.

Once again, the labor shortage came to bite. Unlike in Potosí, there was no mita system, and the native Taino population had a nasty habit (from the Spanish standpoint) of either running off, or, more likely, dying from imported European diseases. Where would the labor come from to plant, harvest and manufacture the sugar crop, especially since demand for it seemed to be insatiable?

Slavery, obviously, combined with large amounts of European bonded labor. If you fell into debt in Europe during this period, you might very well find yourself on a sugar plantation somewhere in the Caribbean.

And it was here in the Caribbean where the first factories were born:

Sugar cane, Saccharum officinarum, has the peculiarly problematic characteristic that its sucrose starts to decay immediately after the cane is harvested. This required the farmers to press the sweet juice from the cane as soon as possible after cutting the cane. Shipping the cane for processing to a nearby urban area, let alone all the way to Europe, was was done with cotton, would destroy the product. Each plantation needed its own sugar mill to grind the cane and to boil the residue down to a crystalline brown sugar.

The plantation functioned more like what we today think of as a factory than like a traditional European farm or manor. . . Since the sugar cane took one and a half years to mature, the plantation operators had to break the traditional cycle of seasons characteristic of European agriculture. Because of the need to process the cane immediately after harvesting, the harvesting had to be staggered so that too much cane came ripe at the same moment. This made sugar cane culture even for field workers a continuous rather than a seasonal or sporadic activity.

Stanley Mintz describes the sugar plantations as a “synthesis of field and factory” in a form that was “quite unlike anything known in mainland Europe at the time.” The cane had to be crushed, and then go through the stages of reduction, clarification, molding, and crystallization in a carefully synchronized and very exact procedure involving mills, giant furnaces, and boiling cauldrons. This highly skilled part of the work required about 10 percent of the total workers of a plantation. Mintz describes this as “the closest thing to industry that was typical of the seventeenth century.” Even though the final refining of sugar into a white substance was completed in England, the plantations of the Caribbean were essentially sugar factories…

The close connection of sugar-cane plantations to factories is seen even in the nomenclature. In Portuguese, sugar mills are called eghenos de assucar, which means “engines of sugar.” Even in English the term sugar mill emphasizes the industrial rather than the agricultural aspect of the enterprise. IG pp. 52-53

And nothing would go to waste: the mills often had a distillery on hand to make rum and molasses. Sugar, syrup, molasses, and rum all came out of the mills from a single agricultural input—sugar cane. One is reminded of later oil refineries, which produced all sorts of distillates from petroleum. Gasoline, which came to predominate, was originally a waste product from the production of kerosene for lamps. In fact, modern sugar processing facilities do look like oil refineries.
The idea that sugar production was the first rollout of the factory system is also echoed by Kenneth Pomeranz. In the book The World That Trade Created, he titles one of his chapters, Sweet Industry: The First Factory:

Already in the seventeenth century, sugar plantations involved perhaps two hundred slaves and freemen, with a mill, boiling house, curing house, distillery for rum, and storehouse. This involved not only some of the most sophisticated technology of the era, and a large workforce, but also investment of several thousand pounds.

True, nine-tenths of the workforce were field hands engaged in brute labor. But the 10 percent in the crushing, boiling, and distilling plants were very much specialized labor. More importantly, the scale, complexity, and social organization of the sugar mills made them into the first factories.

Time was a ruthless master in the sugar production process. Once harvested, cane had to be rushed to the mill to prevent the loss of sugar content. In the mills, especially the larger ones, close care of temperature was necessary. The boilers’ fires had to be constantly stoked; the liquid sugar had to be moved from kettle to kettle without permitting unwanted crystallization, while running off the sediment at the right time. Then the sugar had to be quickly brought to the curing house where the molasses was run off. Sugarcane produced various qualities of sugar, as well as molasses and rum. The closer to attention to production, the better the final product and the greater the returns…

This led to sugar mills becoming the first factories ruled by the discipline of industrial time. The specialized work gangs had to coordinate their efforts: cane had to be quickly cut when mature; carters had to carry it to the mill; the hungry crushers were constantly fed cane; the leftover cane, the bagasse, was carried to the boiling room to stoke the fire.

The time exigencies of the production process meant that slaves had to work together as so many part of a well-oiled machine. Efficiency and slavery, labor saving and labor intensification were combined…

Sugar, which we think of as a leisure and pleasure product, an import from the balmy Caribbean lands of mañana, was actually the first industrial product and a cruel master to the hundreds of thousands of slaves who labored to turn out sweet delights. Marx observed that “the veiled slavery of the wage-workers of Europe needed, for its pedestal, slavery pure and simple in the New World.” He could have added that the factories of the Caribbean were holding a mirror in which Europe could see its industrial future.

The World That Trade Created, pp. 227-228

It was regularized product produced for the market, made by a series of steps in a sort of assembly line fashion, involving large amounts both skilled and unskilled labor under strict supervision, who were slaves to the clock. And it required large amount of upfront expenses to get going. Yep, sounds like a factory to me.

Because it was so very labor-intensive and involved so much upfront investment in equipment and technology, sugar was at first very expensive. So why did it become so popular, then? Well, it turns out it’s addictive. Very addictive.

People often jokingly compare it to another white powder that did originate in the New World-cocaine. The thing is, it’s no joke. Studies have shown that sugar is nearly as biologically addictive as cocaine. Sugar activates the mesolimbic dopamine system, causing a similar dopamine hit as various addictive drugs. Quitting sugar can cause cravings and withdrawal symptoms.

With the industrialization of the food supply in the twentieth century, food companies used this fact to add sweeteners to all their products, ushering in an epidemic of diabetes, obesity, and dental caries.

This leads back to a point I’ve emphasized before: it tends to be the use and procurement of psychoactive and addictive substances that drives social change throughout human history, going all the way back to alcohol.

When sugar first arrived on the tables of the European upper class, it was used as a sculptural medium. As Braudel reports, “On 18 October 1513, the king of Portugal offered the Pope a lifesize sugar effigy of himself, surrounded by twelve cardinals and three hundred candles, one and a half metres high – all made by a long-suffering confectioner” (p. 191).

The Factory System comes to Europe

It may have begun with slaves and bonded labor on the islands of the Caribbean, but it didn’t stay there.

Fernand Braudel introduced a four-fold classification of European manufacturing developed by historian Hubert Bourgin in 1924 (pp. 298-302):

Category A: Tiny family workshops, countless in number and grouped in ‘clusters’, each with a mater tradesman, two or three journeymen and one or two apprentices, a family in itself.

Category B: Workshops which were scattered, but connected to each other–‘dispersed factories’.

Category C: Concentrated manufacture.

Category D: Factories equipped with machinery, using the additional energy sources of running water and steam.

He notes:

So there are the four categories, four types of production in roughly chronological order, although ‘while they followed one upon the other, these different structures did not immediately replace each other’…There certainly was no natural and logical transition from the manufactory to the factory. p. 302

England had been a major center for wool since the Middle Ages. Tudor kings increasingly pursued what we would today call an “industrial policy” in an attempt to make England a producer of the finished product rather than just raw materials for the continent. The investments in cloth production came just in time to be increasingly used for the production of cotton instead of wool, as cotton began pouring in from the New World. Sea Island cotton was particularly desirable.

The techniques first developed on the island plantations of the Caribbean increasingly were imported back into Europe. Instead of sugar, it was first put to use as a way to weave the huge amounts of cotton that were arriving from the Americas into cotton cloth. Since cloth production became the major factory industry back in the Old World, it was cloth production that became mechanized first and fastest, despite deep resistance from labor. The mechanization of cloth production is well-known by now: the power loom, the spinning Jenny, etc.

Eric Wolf discusses the inherent limitations of cottage industry (Braudel’s Category B above), and why it increasingly led to the expanding use of factories (categories C and D):

The advent of the factory was a consequence of the limitations of the putting out system.

That system, in which a merchant entrepreneur furnished raw materials to have them processed in many small household establishments, encountered serious difficulties in sustaining and expanding the scale and scope of operations. It therefore set limits on the accumulation of capital.

There were limits to the intensity and duration of labor where producers worked in scattered and unsupervisable economic units. This was especially true as long as industrial operations supplanted agricultural tasks, such that work in the fields could take precedence over work on spinning wheel and loom. Similarly, religious activities, kinship events, and recreation could, and did, interfere with work intensity and procedures.

Furthermore, the merchant had little defense against pilfering and embezzlement of raw materials by the dispersed workers and little control over quality of output–both problems that grew increasingly serious in the course of the eighteenth century.

The lack of synchronization among the different steps in the sequence of production added to the cost of transportation: when spinning was slow, the merchant-coordinator had to go in search of spinners to feed the looms; when spinning had improved through innovations, merchants had to go in search of hand-loom weavers. There were delays in processing and deliveries, which slowed the turnover time of capital and left customers dissatisfied.

Ever-rising large-scale trade thus encountered the limitations of a productive system divided into innumerable small-scale workshop units, “unsupervised and unsupervisable”. The answer to this contradiction was the establishment of the capitalist factory. Wolf, pp. 274-275

The factory had no such limitations. All of the operations were now located “under one roof” and could be supervised accordingly. Now workers could labor practically non-stop to supply products to the expanding market. The similarities between slavery and wage slavery were not accidental—quite the contrary:

Just as the plantations consisted of a small nucleus of slave barracks clustered around central warehouses and the production area, the European factory clustered workers’ houses around a centralized manufacturing site. This new spatial arrangement replaced the traditional organization of manufacturing in Europe in which individual craftsmen worked in individual workshops or homes.

The new European factory modeled itself on the American plantation. The centralization of workers obviated the need for costly transportation to distribute raw materials to scattered households and workshops and to pick up finished goods. Centralization also helped the owners impose uniformity of work and production on industrial laborers much as the plantation owners had already done with the African and Indian slaves. IG pp. 54-55

Categories C and D increasingly became increasingly prominent. But these manufacturing techniques did not develop out of what had come before. Rather, they were competitors to it, and soon came to supplant the other types of fabrication:

Some people erroneously assume that the European factory grew naturally out of the traditional European craft system as some sort of inevitable cultural evolution. As Peter Kropotkin pointed out quite decisively, the factory system competed with the craft system and did not derive from it. He showed how the Swiss watchmakers doggedly resisted the sale of machine-made watches and how the Lyon silk workers fought adamantly against manufactured silks.

The technology of mass production of goods completely contradicted the principles of the craft tradition, which relied on the apprentice working first toward journeyman and then craftsman status. Kropotkin pointed out that that in contrast to that tradition, the factory system depended on unskilled labor that even a child could and often did perform.

In the end he realized that the crafts would continue only as a source of goods for the aristocracy while factory goods would be for working-class people. Kropotkin decried the unnecessary centralization and urbanization of industrialization and strongly advocated a highly industrialized but decentralized mode of production instead. This he felt would be much more in keeping with both the agricultural and craft heritage of European manufacturing history. Kropotkin did not explain the origins of this alien mode of production—the alien factory which bore so little resemblance to anything else then existent in European society. IG p. 55

Since plantations had been staffed and run by slaves, would the new factories use slave labor as well? This was actually tried in parts of the the New World when the factory system was expanded to other industries besides sugar. But in the end it failed because it turns out that it is cheaper to rent your slaves instead of buying them:

The slave factory system failed in past because the owners could not compete with the much cheaper goods manufactured in New England and Europe. The capitalist system relied on paid laborers to run the factories, and these proved much cheaper than slave laborers. Factory owners had to pay only the one person, often a child, in the family who worked, and had to pay for only as many years as the worker actually produced. Slavery proved too expensive a system to operate in a factory. IG p. 56

Seen from this standpoint, it was the development of an alternative—and more efficient—means of worker control and labor exploitation that led to the demise of slavery, and not noble humanitarian sentiment as is often claimed, i.e. “the better angels of our nature.”

The workers themselves were forced into the factories by the Enclosure Movement. As fields became enclosed and agricultural techniques improved, yeoman farming became less and less of a viable way of life, and the deracinated farmers and agricultural workers poured into metastasizing cities and became the grist for the first Industrial Revolution. Just like the Indians of the New world, however, the destruction of what had been a stable, convivial way of life led to grief, culture shock, and very often, mass deaths, something subsequent history has deliberately swept under the rug in its efforts to validate and normalize capitalism as a “natural” way of life.

Wage labor, while it had always existed to some extent, now became a way of life for most lower-class people as workers became dependent upon factory wages to buy their food and clothing instead of producing it themselves. Those unable to earn money were originally given outdoor relief, but that was soon replaced by workhouses, creating a mass market for labor for the first time in the early 1800s.

As Polanyi noted, the mechanization of production was a necessary catalyst for the creation of Market Society, where custom, sociability and morals were swept aside in favor of theoretically self-regulating forces of supply and demand. This emerging system was defended by intellectuals who never had to set foot in a factory (and still is today).

But the change was traumatic. Agricultural workers were used to working in time with the seasons, having copious time off, and social drinking. They were not used to having every move they made watched, being slaves to a clock, and harsh worker “discipline.” Factory owners themselves acknowledged that they were fighting a war against basic human nature—a war they subsequently won. Eric Wolf writes:

The early British textile factories were faced, however, with a general unwillingness on the part of the potential laboring class to enter into factory employment. Above all, they resisted the unrelenting labor and discipline of the factories, so much at odds with earlier habits and with older customs of sociability and of autonomous labor.

Many early factories were modeled on penal workhouses and prisons, and indeed were manned by involuntary pauper apprentices. The identification of the factory with forced penal labor also meant that former artisans or laborers in cottage industry felt a loss in social status in moving from the relative self-determination of the cottage producer to the servitude of the industrial worker. Indeed, “as long as there was some measure of freedom of choice between cottage and factory the workmen preferred the cottage.” p. 276

The role of state power in establishing the factory system has been covered up by the inherent libertarian biases of the “science” of economics. In economics curricula, history has been eliminated in favor of abstract theorizing and mathematization of idealized utopian markets.

Return to Kahl

To round out the chapter, Weatherford returns to his exemplar village of Kahl in Bavaria. European mills were often located on waterways. This not only facilitated the transport of grain, but also allowed mills to take advantage of water power, as was the case in Kahl.

As long as Europe depended primarily on wool for clothing, peasants could spin it and weave it with simple home technology. The bottleneck in cloth manufacture was the amount of wool that the land was capable for producing, not the ability of the weavers to make cloth. Since the number of sheep determined the amount of wool for weaving, peasants lacked incentives to develop machines or more efficient ways to make clothing.

This situation changed with the massive influx of cotton from America. Suddenly, the peasants and the weavers had more fiber than they could weave. They lacked the labor to process so much fiber. Europe desperately needed more energy than it had in human and animal power, and the most readily available source for creating new energy lay in the waterwheels already in place throughout the continent. Thus were born the first textile factories. IG p. 43

As Weatherford documents, the mills were utilized less and less as the peasant diet increasingly switched from cereals to potatoes, which, unlike grain, did not require milling. The mills—powered by water—were then put to other uses. As the factory system expanded and machines became utilized more and more, it made sense to locate factories in what had previously been grain processing mills. Water power now drove the machines of weaving such as the spinning mule.

The citizens of Kahl increasingly abandoned their farms and fields and went to work in the factories producing goods for distant markets:

Early in the nineteenth century, after Kahl recovered from the disasters of the Napoleonic conquests, imaginative entrepreneurs discovered new uses for the mills of Kahl. The mills offered a great source of energy, and this energy could be applied to other purposes than the mere grinding of grains or pressing of oils; the energy could be harnessed to power looms to make cloth.

Gradually the mills throughout the area were converted into small factories producing textiles, matches, electrical fuses, and felt, and eventually they were renovated to produce electricity, felt-making machines, and more complex electrical equipment… IG p. 42

Of course, if the peasants abandoned their fields, they would nevertheless still have to eat. Where would the food come from?

Increasingly, food was imported from the vast breadbaskets of North America and the Russian plains. This freed up the agricultural workers to become factory workers. In fact, the agricultural revolution was a prerequisite to the industrial revolution, something a lot of historians miss completely.

Of course, with plentiful supplies of grain flooding into Europe from abroad, the price of grain dropped. Large landholders advocated for price supports to keep the price high enough so that they could earn a living; industrialists, on the other hand, wanted it cheap so they could pay their workers less. In England, this took the form of debates over the Corn Laws. This was fundamentally a power conflict between the old landowning aristocracy and the rising industrialist class.

There’s a fascinating story in how the Industrial Revolution was also made possible by a food revolution. That included foodstuffs from the New World and the expansion of arable lands that conquest and colonialism engendered. It also featured improved agricultural techniques in Europe as well. But that’s a story for another time.

In the end, the industrialists won out. The price of grain dropped too low for small European farmers to make a living, so they threw in the towel and moved to the city. This led to mass poverty and overcrowding. These individuals and families became the proletariat of the first Industrial Revolution, a time of wrenching social change, similar to today, where the average worker was thrown under the bus with little to no resources to fall back on and told to fend for him or herself. Like today, living standards went down and the death rate went up.

With the invention of an efficient steam engine in the late 1700s by James Watt, heat engines could then be harnessed to factories which were located far away from wind and water power. Thus out of the factory system and mechanization of labor is born the industrial revolution based around fossil fuels that we are familiar with:

Soon the manufacturing in Kahl surpassed the capacity of the waterwheels to supply power, and the villagers began excavating local deposits of low-quality brown coal to produce electricity and thus increase the power available to them. After they exhausted the coal veins, the village switched to nuclear power to generate electricity. Throughout this process the emergent industries stimulated the development of collateral businesses such as construction and thus heightened the demand for lumber, stone, brick, sand, gravel, cement and other raw materials.

The industrialization of Kahl illustrated in miniature the process that occurred throughout England, Germany, and the other European nations. America supplied the raw materials for the revolution, and the sugar-cane plantations of the Caribbean and mines and mints of Mexico and the Andes supplied the prototypes for the first factories.

This initiated the industrial revolution in Europe; later in the nineteenth century a new stage based on coal and its derivatives replaced the first stage. This in time was superseded by the oil revolution when petroleum products became not only major sources of fuel but the source of may new raw materials, such as dyes, plastics, synthetic fibers, and a side array of chemicals. p. 57

Finally, there was a nuclear power plant, financed by the Versuchsatomkraftwerk Kahl GmbH. In a little more than a century the wooden water wheel had been replaced by the nuclear reactor. All this began with the adoption of the potato, but obviously the process involved many more factors than the mere potato, since the Peruvians have had potatoes for thousands of years but still do not have atomic energy. p. 42

But it all began with the need of European colonizers the New World to deal with a chronic labor shortage and to create products for export that were labor intensive to produce. So it was the New World that pioneered the factory system. Kenneth Pomeranz sums it up:

When we think of the first factories, we usually think of Europe, particularly England. After all, factories were the definition of “modern: and Europe was the leader in modernization. We assume that they were first built in Europe, where capital, machines, and labor combined to create ever-more efficient and productive methods. European ingenuity and entrepreneurship together with previously accumulated capital and budding markets led to the industrialization that was the secret of Europe’s centuries long domination of the world economy.

According to this story, the globe was divided between industrial Europe, and later the United States, and the agrarian exporting rest of the world. With this international specialization of labor, the agricultural countries only belatedly industrialized.

In fact, there is good reason to turn this version on its head: the first factories arose in the colonial, export-oriented world. p. 226

So to answer the original question of why the industrial revolution happened when and where it did, the reason is because it was Western European powers who established colonies in far-flung locations including the Caribbean, Brazil (the center of sugar production), and the American South. It was Europe that has an insatiable appetite for exotic products like sugar and cotton. Thus it was the Europeans who developed the mechanization processes and brutal worker coercion to produce those products to cope with the shortage of labor in the New World, as well of the lack of competing social arrangements as was the case in Europe. It was the development of this harsh system, and its importation back into Western Europe–especially in the area of cloth production–that were the necessary prerequisites for everything that followed–mechanization, marketization and fossil fuel power. This unique series of circumstances was only present in Western Europe thanks to its invasion and colonization of the tropics after 1500.

Those techniques of worker control never went away. The means of controlling workers developed linearly into the conditions almost all of us labor under to this very day. We’ll take a look at that next time, after a brief detour though industrialization’s effect on urban life.

(Braudel quotes are from The Wheels of Commerce, Civilization and Capitalism 15th-18th Century Volume 2) Eric Wolf quotes are from Europe and the People Without History.

The Origin of the Factory 1

There has been an ongoing debate over what the industrial revolution was, and whether it required the introduction of fossil fuels.

On first glance, it may seem like, of course fossil fuels were required. How else could the vast amount of output of the industrial revolution be achieved?

Not so, say those who argue the opposite. The argue that the industrial revolution was well under way long before fossil fuels entered the picture.

Rather, the industrial revolution was really all about the reorganization, intensification, and mechanization of human labor, they say. During the industrial revolution, labor was transformed into something closer to what we know today—large amounts of people toiling under the same roof, each doing their own specialized part of the production process instead of individually crafting things from scratch. Deskilling, specialization, routinization, mechanization, and harsh worker “discipline”—these were all aspects of the Industrial Revolution’s reorganization of working life that did not require the introduction of fossil fuels.

Similarly the use of machines first kicked off with human and animal power, and then later moved to water and wind. It was only after centuries of this when steam engines replaced them and fossil fuels became the prime energy mover. By the time fossil-fuel-powered engines came along, the argument goes, they merely had to be plugged in to system that had already been put into place.

In large measure, they have the timeline right. The reorganization, routinization, deskilling and mechanization of labor did indeed precede the steam engine. Early factories were established before the large-scale harnessing of fossil fuels, and output did go up a great deal.

In this case, it’s helpful to distinguish, as some historians do, several industrial revolutions. How it’s divided up varies depending on the historian. But generally, a distinction is made between the birth of the factory system; the mass utilization of coal and steam engines; the use of gasoline and the internal combustion engine; and the harnessing of electricity and the application of scientific research and engineering methods to the creation of new products.

But the question remains, where did this reorganization of labor first originate?

The New World Path to Industrialization

It turns out that it originated in the New World. From there, it spread to the Europe.

That’s the contention in a book called Indian Givers by Jack Weatherford. Weatherford is best known for his series of books about Genghis Khan and the Mongols. But before he wrote those, his specialty was Native American history, and he wrote several books about the topic.

Chapter Two of Indian Givers is called “The American Indian Path Towards Industrialization.” At first glance, it might seem odd to talk about an “American Indian path to Industrialization,” as the American Indians were less, not more, technologically advanced then the European invaders (with some notable exceptions).

But it was a combination of circumstances caused by the exploitation of New World resources, as well as the discovery of new resources that played the critical role. As he puts it,

“Without European technology and organization, the industrial revolution would never have started in America; without American precious metals and methods of processing, the industrial revolution would never have happened in Europe.” p. 58

Weatherford uses as his illustration the village of Kahl in Germany. For a long time a small farming village, it industrialized during the great rolling industrialization of the nineteenth century. Today, alongside quaint village houses, fenced farm fields, and abandoned mills, sit factories, ports, railroads, truck depots, and even a nuclear power plant! What changed, and why did it change so rapidly in just the last couple of centuries?

Farm life in Kahl remained much the same regardless of whether the village was inhabited by Celts, the Chatten, the Romans, or the Franks. A peasant would probably have felt equally at home farming in the Kahl of 700 B.C. or A.D. 1700.

In this time the basic subsistence pattern of agriculture—the crops grown, the animals used, and the tools for growing and processing them—remained basically unaltered. The houses of the peasants from the two eras differed little, the peasants moved around by the same modes of transportation, and they ate roughly the same meals.

Suddenly in the last few centuries, life changed radically after millennia of great technological stability. The peasants stopped working in the fields and started to work in factories. They illuminated their houses and other buildings with electricity, and they replaced their horses with bicycles, tractors and trucks. They altered their diet, and the way they built their homes and educated their children. Within a few generations, virtually every aspect of life changed… IG pp. 40-41

Weatherford asks a question you hear often today: why did technologically advanced and sophisticated ancient cultures not break through to have their own industrial revolution? Why did it take (from our standpoint) so long? If we don’t require fossil fuel power or steam engines to have an industrial revolution, as we saw above, then what was stopping them?

After thousands of years of agricultural life, this sudden leap into the industrialized world seems difficult to explain. Why had the Greeks, with so much mathematical and philosophical learning and such outstanding architectural techniques, not been able to make and use machines? Why were the Romans, with all of their technical and practical knowledge of engineering and their vast array of engines of war, not industrialized? Why could the people of the Renaissance, who demonstrated their mechanical wizardry by making elaborate toys, not make the leap into machine production? What happened to the world in the 1700s and 1800s to make it industrialize after thousands of static years of technological stability? Indian Givers, p. 41

Weatherford’s answer is that the encounter with the New World was the catalyst. This was the missing piece from all earlier eras of world history.

Why was this the case? Well, this was simply based on the fact that the New World had a chronic shortage of labor. The Old World did not.

In fact, it’s highly unlikely that such a shortage would ever have transpired in the old civilizational centers of Eurasia. They also would have not been developed sui generis by people in the New World.

No, it took an invasion to do that. An invasion combined with a labor shortage.

In fact, the Old World had a surfeit of labor throughout most of history. That surfeit of labor would end up becoming the labor stock for the first industrial revolution.

But first, the factory system had to be invented.

Labor shortage

Unlike the Old World, the New World suffered from chronic and persistent shortage of labor.

There was a vast pool of resources just sitting around that needed processing, but the people who lived there kept inconveniently dying just when the exploiters needed them the most.

So, the conquerors were forced by necessity to come up with new ways of organizing labor due to the chronic shortage. Because of the labor shortage, Europeans in the New World developed all sorts of new and novel techniques to extract the maximum amount of labor out of their limited workforce—by and large enslaved Indians and Africans, with indentured workers (bonded labor) thrown into the mix.

In this case, necessity was the mother of invention. History shows that things typically aren’t invented until there’s some sort of pressing need for it.

You might say the New World products were the tinder, and the labor shortage was the spark.

The Americas in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries promised vast resources—gold, silver, and furs, as well as the seemingly inexhaustible potential for crops of tobacco, sugarcane, rice, coffee, indigo, and hundreds of other plants. But a major obstacle constantly slowed the extraction of both the metals and agricultural treasures from the ground: the persistent shortage of labor.

The Spanish quickly impressed the Indians into slave labor, but in some areas, such as the Caribbean islands and Central America, the Indians died very quickly from diseases, malnutrition, overwork, or simple culture shock and grief. In other cases the natives lacked sufficient experience in agriculture or mining to be acculturated into the new Spanish system as workers.

No matter how many slaves the British and Dutch shipped to America, the plantation and mine owners demanded more laborers. Because of the lack of sufficient manpower, the Americans improvised whole new mechanical technologies to help tap the natural resources and potential wealth. IG, p. 49

Back in the days of cottage industries, artisanal production, and small, individual workshops, it was unlikely that anyone would have seen a need to scale up their operations very much, or dramatically increase their output, as there would not have been enough customers to buy their products even if they were to do so.

With the introduction of vast new amounts of silver into the Old World, and the marketization of society it engendered, suddenly not only was there a huge amount of new products, but there was also the money with which to buy them! This catalyzed a self-sustaining feedback loop—more money demanded more products, which made more money, which was invested into higher output of products. The New World produced not only the products, but also the money with which to buy the products. Supply really did create its own demand:

At the time of the discovery of the Americas, Europe had only about $200 million worth of gold and silver, approximately $2 per person. By 1600 the supply of precious metals had increased approximately eightfold. The Mexican mint alone coined $2 billion worth of silver prices of eight.

The silver coins flowing through Europe at first promised to strengthen the feudal order, but in the end they forged whole new classes and changed the fortunes of many countries. The new coins helped to wash away the old aristocratic order in which money games could be played only by the privileged few; massively larger amounts of money opened up new games to new people.

Even though all the gold and silver went into Spain, it did not stay there. From Spain the money spread throughout Europe. The Hapsburg monarch Charles V occupied his throne both as emperor of the Holy Roman Empire and as the king of Spain; this facilitated the spread of the money from Spain to the Hapsburg holdings in the Spanish Netherlands and across Germany, Switzerland, Austria, and the Italian states. Three-fifths of the bullion entering Spain from America immediately left Spain to pay debts, mostly those incurred by the profligate monarchy…

Precious metals from the Americas superseded land as the basis for wealth, power and prestige. For the first time there was enough of some commodity other than land to provide a greater and more consistent standard by which wealth might be measured. This easily transported and easily used means of wealth prepared the way for the new merchant and capitalist class that would soon dominate the whole world…

The tremendous volume of new currency influenced the economy of all Europe. For example, in Naples there wee only 700,000 ducats in circulation and in savings in 1570. In less than two centuries, by 1751, there were eighteen million ducats. These eighteen million ducts, moreover, could be used many times in a year for various types of transactions. The total number of ducats used in buying and selling would be approximately 288 million.

Similarly, in France, which received its wealth from the New World much later than Spain, approximately 120 million francs circulated in 1670, but by 1770 there were two billion in circulation, a fifteenfold increase in a century. IG, pp. 14-16

Not only did they ship over products from the New World like cotton, tobacco and coffee, but they also shipped over the means to buy those same products in the form of silver and gold bullion.

There was tremendous bounty in the New World, it was true, yet New World goods needed a lot of work to process, that is, they were labor intensive. Where would the labor to do all this work come from?

Slavery, obviously. But even slaves can only do so much. Plus, they’re expensive. You’ve got to ship them over from Africa, buy them, feed and clothe them, and so forth. The same is true for bonded labor. Plus, unlike artisans, you’re not dealing with skilled labor here. You’re dealing with simply warm bodies, ripped from their culture and with little to no training in what they are about to do.

So, to minimize the number of slaves you needed to buy (and the bonded labor you need to indenture), and to dumb down the process enough so that they could easily be put to work, you need to maximize labor output and simplify your tasks. And thus the idea of capitalist efficiency was born—maximizing productive output with the absolute minimum of labor input.

In order to do that, you need to reorganize labor and use machines to the greatest extent possible. This is why this process began in the Americas, rather than in the Old World. In particular, it began in the sugar mills of the Americas—large ,extensive operations designed to grow and harvest sugarcane and turn it into the raw material to be shipped back to Europe and sold for profit.

Even though most of the labor was unskilled, you still needed a small class of skilled laborers for supervision, as well as to direct the more precise industrial processes. So you end up with a balance of about 90 percent unskilled labor versus 10 percent skilled labor in the sugar mills, very similar to that in the earliest factories.

And another key ingredient was the impetus to mass production that New World crops gave to European markets. All sort of new products were discovered during the Columbian exchange-tobacco, chocolate, cotton, dyes, rubber, sisal, etc. These were combined with products already known to Europeans but that Europeans were unable to produce themselves because they required a tropical clime—things like like coffee, sugar and cotton, especially.

While cotton was previously known to Europeans, it turns out that cotton was domesticated independently by natives in the New World, and their cotton was of much higher quality than that in the Old World. The strands were longer, smoother, and silkier; so silky, in fact, that Europeans mistook some Indian cotton garments for silk! Cotton cloaks were used as a high-denomination currency in Mesoamerica, alongside lower-denomination cacao beans.

Some Old World types of cotton had been grown in India and the Near East for centuries, but only very small quantities of it ever reached Europe. This cotton was not only expensive, but weak and difficult to weave because of its short strands.

Asiatic cottons, Gossypium herbaceum and G. arboreum, had a strand length of only about half an inch, but American upland cotton, G. hirtutum, usually grew a full inch or more. Meanshile, G. barbodense, the tropical American cotton that became best known as Sea Island cotton (from the plantations that grew it on the coast of South Carolina and Georgia), could grow to two and a half inches.

In Europe the short strands of the Old World cotton served primarily for padding jerkins under the coats of mail worn in battle. In time the uses of cotton expanded to the making of fustian, which was a coarse material built on a warp of stronger flax and a woof of Old World cotton. Not until American cotton arrived in England, however, did the phrase “cotton cloth” appear in English; the Oxford English Dictionary’s earliest date for it is 1552.

The long-strand cotton of the American Indians so surpassed in quality the puny cotton of the Old World that the Spaniards mistook the American cloth for silk and interpreted its abundance as yet further proof that these new lands lay close to China.

For thousands of years before the European conquest of America the Indians had been using this carefully developed cotton to weave some of the finest textiles in the world. Many remnants of these early cloths survive to the present day, their colors and designs intact, after several thousand years in the desert burials of Peru, Bolivia, and Chile. IG, pp. 42-42

I’m not going to go deep into the history of New World products or foods. Instead, I’d like to take a look at how the labor shortage forced the Europeans to automate many of the processes they used with enslaved New World labor, and how this led to the development of the factory system in Europe. In particular, we’ll look at two critical New World industries: mining and sugar production.

The Nature of Unemployment

While doing some research on History Stack Exchange, I came across this answer concerning unemployment, and I thought it was relevant to share here:

There is no such thing as a “labor shortage”. “Labor Shortage” is just a propaganda term used by employers who are trying to find some excuse to pay less.

For example, many manufacturers complain that there is a “shortage” of machinists. What this means is that they would like to pay machinists $10 an hour and, surprise, surprise, no machinist wants to work for $10 an hour. If the manufacturer offered $100 an hour, he would have machinists coming out of his ears. He would have machinists lining up at his front door wanting to work for him. He would have machinists flying from all over the world to work at his factory.
Likewise, employees use the same political language. They say there is a “job shortage”. Of course, there is no job shortage. If you are willing to work for $5 an hour you will find hundreds of employers willing to hire you. In fact, for $5 an hour * I * will hire you.

There is no such thing “labor shortages” and “job shortages”. They are just made up terms used by people for political purposes.

https://history.stackexchange.com/a/12977

That’s an interesting take on it. Of course, there might be a true labor shortage if there literally weren’t enough people to keep society running, in which case we would have zero unemployment. This would be an “all hands on deck” situation where everyone’s labor is required simply to survive.

Another phrase you’ll often hear is that we need to import people to the jobs “Americans won’t do.” Well, they would do them if you paid them well enough. The fact is, this is just an excuse by employers to keep wages low.

Another exchange clarifies the point:

I think he meant labour shortage in the sense that there were actually more available jobs than workers. – Saal Hardali May 27 ’14 at 17:49

You don’t seem to get it. There are an infinite “number of jobs”. If you and your friends agree to work for me for 25 cents an hour I will hire you all, even if you have a thousand friends. I just “created” 1000 jobs instantly. You seem to have the erroneous idea that “jobs” are some kind of fixed commodity. A “job” is just some guy willing to pay some other guy to do something. – Tyler Durden May 27 ’14 at 18:08

Another question asks whether there was unemployment in ancient Rome. The commenter answers that what we think of as “unemployment” was not relevant to earlier pre-capitalist societies::

The modern definition of unemployed is “having looked for work recently”. I’m not entirely sure that definition is appropriate for Rome. Modern Western Liberal Democracy is organized around the notion that “companies” provide employment, and that people seek employment. Unemployment results in a dramatic decline in economic and social status.

Although there were workshops in Rome, and there were teams that organized to perform tasks that no individual could, I’m not aware of anything that resembles the modern limited liability corporation. Roman politics and economics were based more on relationships than on companies. Romans belonged to a family, and to a tribe, and usually to some kind of patron/client relationship. Depending on their social class, they may have also belonged to one or more social organizations (e.g. burial society). If someone wanted to work, they would rely on these connections to find them employment. “Unemployment” didn’t really result in the kind of economic and social decline we find today because these social bonds provided a safety net. If for some reason you were isolated from your social network, that might be a definition similar to “unemployed”, but there were mechanisms (adoption, social organizations, etc.) that made the social networks fairly resilient.

https://history.stackexchange.com/a/12821

There is no unemployment in foraging societies either, for example. Unemployment presumes a market society where we must earn wages or some sort of other income to survive. The wealthy rely on passive income from investments; the rest of us have to sell our labor. And despite the insistence of the “financial independence” crowd (Mr. Money Mustache, et. al.), is is not possible for all members of society to live off of passive income. It also assumes that we have enough surplus in the first place to invest in passive-income generating schemes, which most of us do not by design. We can’t all be six-figure software engineers (in which case, software engineers would not worth very much).

What brought this to mind was this discussion with Warren Mosler over MMT’s counter-intuitive idea that unemployment is actually created by governments, and the unemployment rate is always a policy choice. In other words, it is not like a hurricane or a fire that is out of our control. It is a human-created phenomenon. Here is Mosler explaining some important aspects of the job market:

[15:41] “The labor market is not a fair game, with or without unemployment, because people have to work to eat. Business only hires if they can make a certain return on equity that they think is a good deal, otherwise they don’t hire. Nothing bad happens to them if they don’t hire. And so mainstream, elementary game theory will tell you this is not a fair game, and so you’re going to expect real wages to gravitate towards subsistence levels, whatever that is, unless there’s some support for labor.”

“Now, we used to have a lot of support for labor with labor unions, and then in the 1980’s they were all broken, and that’s when the wedge started being driven between productivity and labor, where the productivity kept going up, but everything started going to profits instead of wages. It’s pretty clear in the data that that’s what happened, because labor lost its support…The principle is that real wages are going to stagnate near subsistence unless you do something to support them because its not a fair game.

“You could have unemployment down to everybody’s got a job except this one last guy who’s unemployed, and then he sees a job offer. Well, he’s got two choices—take the job or his family can’t eat. It’s not like all these other people have jobs so I can demand more money. You look at his position—he’s not in any better position because everybody else has a job. So it’s absolutely not a fair game.

So it shouldn’t be any surprise that wages aren’t going anywhere, even with unemployment coming down. The Philips curve doesn’t seem to be working the way some have suggested…which says as that as you get towards lower and lower unemployment wages will go up and up. It’s just not happening, and that’s why.”

This seems to be lost on nearly all economists, who are stumped by the fact that wages aren’t rising, even in the face of “full” employment. But why would they?

The economy may be booming, but nearly half of Americans can’t make ends meet (L.A. Times)

The fall in those wages has alarmed some economists, who say paychecks should be getting fatter at a time when unemployment is low and businesses are hiring. “This is odd and remarkable,” said Steven Kyle, an economist at Cornell University. “You would not normally see this kind of thing unless there were some kind of external shock, like a bad hurricane season, but we haven’t had that.”

The falling wages promise to exacerbate historic levels of U.S. inequality. Within the labor force, it means workers who were already making less are falling further behind. And if private laborers as a whole are seeing their earnings flatten while the economy as a whole grows at an annual rate of more than 2 percent, that means the gains are going almost exclusively to people already at the top of the economic ladder, economists say

For the biggest group of American workers, wages aren’t just flat. They’re falling. (Washington Post)

Then Mosler explains the basics about why unemployment is an artificial creation of the state, rather than a “natural” phenomenon. In doing so, he explains the origin of money, and what the public debt really is—the money supply:

[26:20] “The other critically important contribution of Modern Monetary Theory is that the cause of unemployment, by design, is taxation…The monetary circuit theory begins with businesses borrowing money to hire people. MMT says, no, the money story begins before then. Why is anybody working for this money to begin with? Where does the money story start? It starts with a government trying to provision itself.

“We show examples like when the British colonized Ghana. They wanted to grow coffee there. How do you do it? What you have is a state—the British at the time—that wanted to move resources, which was human labor, from whatever these people were doing in Ghana before they got there in a non-monetary society. They wanted to get them into the coffee fields…”

“What the British did was they implemented a tax. They started a new currency—let’s call it the crown—and so they offered crowns for people who wanted to come work in the coffee field. But nobody wanted to work for crowns, nobody had ever heard of it; there’s no reason to give up hunting and fishing and taking care of the children to go down to the coffee fields and pick coffee for this crown thing…So what they did was, they implemented a hut tax. They all lived in these grass huts. They said there’s going be a ten crown a month tax on every hut, and if the hut doesn’t pay its tax, we’re going to go burn it down. They had the military.”

“So now they’ve created this tax liability – everybody has to pay 10 crowns a month or get your house burned down. And so now they’ve created something which didn’t exist before-that’s people looking for paid work in a currency, which is what we call unemployment. Unemployment is not people looking for volunteer work for the American Cancer Society who can’t get a job — it’s people who need money. And it’s created by taxation. In a non-monetary society where you don’t have monetary taxation, there’s no unemployment as we know it. There can’t be. It’s just not applicable.”

And so the taxation, by design, is there to create people who need the currency for the further purpose of provisioning the government — in this case, provisioning the British with labor in their coffee fields. They would then have all these people showing up looking for work in the coffee fields, and now they could hire them and pay in crowns because the people need it to pay the tax. They understood that they had to get paid first before they could pay the tax. The British would spend first and then collect the tax. And, of course, the British would always spend more than they collected, because people would earn the money first, and they would earn more than was needed to pay the tax normally…”

So the British always ran a deficit; they always spent more than they collected, and those extra crowns they spent were called the money supply. Those were the crowns people had in their pockets or in their homes, or the merchants would have them in their shops, and they all knew that the British would spend more than they collected, and that’s where the money supply came from, and that spending more than you collect is called deficit spending, and the amount that you spend that more than you collect is called the public debt, and they all knew the public debt was the money supply, as they casually called it back then. Today we’ve lost sight of that.”

We have twenty trillion of public debt; what is it? It’s not wrong to define it as the money supply for the economy. If the government has spent twenty trillion more than they’ve taxed, and those dollars sit out there in bank accounts, until they get used to pay taxes. So the twenty trillion are the dollars spent by the government that haven’t yet been used to pay taxes. That’s our public debt, and that’s all it is.

The money story starts with the government trying to provision itself, which is very different form the mainstream story.

I did some research into the British efforts in Ghana. What Mosler stated above is confirmed on the BBC’s own Web site:

One of the central pillars of colonisation was tax. The European powers did not want Africa to be a drain on their treasuries, and they wanted the colonies to pay their own way. They also wanted people to enter into the cash economy. Taxation was a way of driving people into working for money.

The competence of a French colonial official might often be measured by how much tax he was able to collect. This could be in the form of a poll tax or a tax on homes. For the ordinary people, especially those who were not earning money through labour or selling goods, taxation was an intolerable burden. Resentment turned to anger in many parts of Africa…

The Story of Africa (BBC)

Here is some more detail about the British and French colonial activities in West Africa: 8: Colonial Rule in West Africa (WASSCE History Textbook)

So the libertarians are partly right where they say that taxes are imposed by state violence. Where they fall down is the fact that these were effectively unmonetized traditional societies before state violence, and not barter economies like Adam Smith imagined. International markets destroyed these societies; they were not an integral part of them, except as supplemental places of surplus exchange. It was the violence itself that created the markets of which libertarians are so deliriously enamored!

They were also created by law. The competitive labor market in Britain was established in 1834, before which, industrial capitalism as a social system did not exist. What Britain did internally it later did externally.

Colonialism and hut taxes destroyed the traditional provisioning methods of these societies. Rather than the traditional subsistence agriculture which had always fed the people, the colonizers wanted farmers to grow cash crops for export. This meant that food producers were now dependent upon the money gained from selling that crop to buy whatever else they needed, including food. And the amount of money they gained from that crop was entirely determined by distant global commodity markets over which they had no control.

Sometimes people wonder how it is that a country like Côte d’Ivoire can produce a nonedible crop such as cocoa but at the same time have difficulty feeding its people. The answer to this question involves two factors: colonialism and the introduction of cash crops.

The European colonial powers in sub-Saharan Africa, most notably France and Britain, expanded indigenous agriculture to include cash crops geared to the wants of European consumers and industries. The production of these cash crops for export depended upon plantation and sharecropper systems. Britain organized the commercial production of cocoa in Ghana, wool and coffee in Kenya, and tea in Zimbabwe. France arranged the production of peanuts in Senegal and Mali, and cocoa and bananas in Côte d’Ivoire.

The economic shift toward cash crops significantly decreased the production of goods for local food needs and at the same time destroyed indigenous handicraft industries.

The kingdom of Bugunda, in what has been Uganda since 1894, provides a good example. Once Bugundan peasants were forced by British colonists to produce cotton and coffee for export, the local barkcloth and pottery crafts disappeared. Likewise, people began working in mines, fields, and plantations for export production in order to pay household or hut taxes and retain access to land. As a consequence, indigenous societies lost cultural knowledge and agricultural production for local food needs declined. Indigenous labor and resources were used to sustain and develop European urban and industrial needs.

Child Labor in Sub-Saharan Africa, by Loretta Elizabeth Bass p. 32

So the “staving African” and “starving Indian” stereotypes were a product of the creation of Market society, and not natural features of their daily existence, and certainly not due to “low IQ” as the Alt-Right race fetishists would have it. The “poverty line” used by international agencies is exclusively determined by the cash income earned by people in these post-colonial economies. The fact that there was no poverty line before colonialism is always ignored. Today, the raising of the poverty line in developing countries is used as the primary defense of Neoliberalism by its supporters.

Capitalist logic defines poverty in strict monetary terms, such as the poverty line, in which people don’t possess enough money to purchase basic goods from the market. In this way, capitalism not only makes people dependent on the market for survival, but also does not acknowledge alternative factors which contribute to human wellbeing, such as health, education, affection, the environment, or life in the community.

The Obsolescence of Capitalism (Medium)

Later, marketing boards were introduced to deal with the random price fluctuations that were the cause of so much misery:

The extraction of the agricultural surplus for urban/industrial development has been a common objective of both colonial and postindependence rule. Colonial authorities imposed various taxes (head taxes, hut taxes) and compulsory planting of selecting export crops to stimulate the production of export crops and to capture the agricultural surplus. Shortly after World War II, the British colonial government introduced marketing boards in their East and West African colonies following the relatively successful record of marketing boards in Australia and New Zealand since the 1930s. The objective of the marketing boards was to stabilize producer prices and foreign exchange earnings and to reduce interseasonal price movements.

In the 1960s and the 1970s, numerous African governments introduced grain boards to control producer prices and food grains and to channel food to the urban centers. Boards usually accumulate and carry stocks to mitigate both intra- and inter-annucal flucturations in price and supply, and develop distribution systems to facilitate the transfer of grain from surplus to deficit regions.

A Survey of Agricultural Economics Literature Volume 4; edited by Lee R. Martin pp. 44-45

A lot of MMT’s recommendations are about creating a “marketing board” for jobs—a “job board” for society was it were, that would stabilize prices and demand for the commodity called “labor”. These would provide ways for people to earn the money that market society requires as a condition of survival rather than leaving it up to the “free” market, which has devastated so many communities across the world.

ADDENDUM: This is tangential, but one of the comments I sometimes see in discussions surrounding economics is something on the order of, “capitalism has always existed…”

Um, no. This is an incredibly ignorant statement, and oblivious to economic history. Yet it’s surprising how many people seem to believe it, or toss it off as if were some sort of obvious statement. It’s only possible if we define capitalism so broadly as to lose all meaning of the term. I thought this comment to an article at the Guardian did a good job of illustrating what’s wrong with this kind of reasoning:

Jesus. Capitalism involves people thinking rationally about their self interest therefore all instances of people thinking rationally about their self interest are engaging in capitalist modes of though.

Football is a sport that involves players running therefore anyone who is running is a football player.

Christmas is a religious festival marked by people exchanging gifts therefore whenever people exchange gifts they are celebrating Christmas.

Demographics Redux

A while back, I wondered if the low unemployment rate was down to simple demographics.

The reason I thought that was this chart:

Look at that peak. The peak plateaus from what I can tell, about 1958-1963. It then falls off a cliff and bottoms out around the year I was born – 1973, and never recovers, despite a very slight uptick in the late 1980’s (the “echo boom”)

While It’s harder to find data for other countries, here’s Canada. It appears to bottom out in the late nineteen-eighties:

In the U.K. it was more of a bactrian instead of dromedary hump, possibly due to the rationing years. But the cliff still occurs at approximately the same time:

Wikipedia has more data on it: Mid-twentieth century baby boom.

It notes that the baby boom was the strongest in Australia and New Zealand, which I didn’t know. It notes that in Europe, it was the strongest in France and Austria, and weakest in Southern Europe. It includes this chart for the United States:

Someone born in 1963 would be 1963 + 2020 = 57. That’s the youngest cohort. The oldest would be those born about 1947. 1947 + 2020 = 73. 55-65 is prime retirement age.

Note that we’re also hearing about how the stock market—where many retirement savings are invested—is at all-time highs. This puts retirement in reach for many baby Boomers.

This means that the people at the bottom of the trough would be my age and younger – 47. Again, note that while it increases slightly, the birth rate never recovers.

Now, I’m told that these are supposedly my “peak” working years. That is, workers in my age range are desirable – not too old, but old enough to acquire experience. But there are hell of a lot less of us than there have been in the very recent past!

That’s before you consider the demographic effects of increased mortality and incarceration which took such a huge toll on people who became adults after the sharp turn to the Right that began with Reagan in 1980. The “deaths of despair” began increasing after the year 2000. That means a lot of people are simply “missing” from the work force due to the tragedies of modern life. I’ve seen a heartbreaking number of people around me dying before their time–people in their thirties, forties and fifties.

When I first posited the idea, some readers had objections to it, and they made very good points. But I still thought that demographics must have some sort of impact, given the charts, above.

What brought this back to my attention was this article posted at TYWKIWDBI, which deals specifically with Minnesota, but is also relevant to the U.S more generally:

The Minnesota economy will also be squeezed as the last baby boomers retire in the decade. The 3 million-person labor force will essentially stop growing in the first five years of the 2020s, demographers say, and pick up only slightly after that.

This leveling off is already being felt across the state. Job vacancies have outnumbered the unemployed in Minnesota for two years. Businesses, governments and ordinary people find it’s harder to get things done. Hiring is especially challenging at restaurants, factories, schools and hospitals. Things aren’t delivered on time.

Such difficulties are mainly seen as effects from an economic upturn that, having started after the 2008-09 recession, has lasted longer than any other. But they’re also a product of the less-understood slowing of population growth…

This pattern is projected to continue into the 2030s and 2040s. There were so many baby boomers that their deaths from old age will offset the number of people being born or immigrating. By 2034, the Census Bureau says there will be more Americans over 65 than under 18. Similar challenges exist around the world. As populations become larger, it’s harder to sustain previous high rates of growth.

Population trends (TYWKIWDBI)

Which confirms the observations I made back then.

The precedent for the overall size of the economy has been set by the Baby Boom. Economies do not like to shrink, if for no other reason than to generate sufficient growth to pay back past loans. Thus, employers will continue to search for enough employees to keep the economy the size it was during the Boomer years with a shrinking pool of workers.

That’s excellent news for us workers, as it places a modicum of power back in our hands instead of being totally on the side of employers. There are the headwinds of automation and globalization to contend with, of course, complicating the situation. But if there is less competition for jobs, perhaps colleges will not be able to turn entire generations of Americans into indentured servants. They will lose their role as guardians and tollbooths to a moderately comfortable middle-class life, which would be a positive development, indeed.

This will, of course, be framed as horrible, horrible in the mainstream media, which is owned by major corporations and run for their benefit. Of course, the reason the media will declare this as a very serious threat is precisely because it benefits workers over capital and threatens to raise wages for workers–a process which is so far being fiercely resisted by big business.

There will be urgent and persistent calls for increased immigration in the mainstream corporate media, especially if there is a trend of rising wages. While Trump’s immigration policies are barbaric, if the average American sees the benefits of a tight labor market, Trump will (unfortunately) remain popular. the Left has really shot themselves in the foot by encouraging mass immigration for the past several decades, which decimated what used to be their base of working-class people, as the chart above shows. Instead, they counted on support from a small niche demographic of wealthy, upper-class urban professionals who did not have to compete with immigrants and benefited from the low wages in the service sector.

That came around to bite them. That’s not enough to win. Immigration was a wedge here in the States, and we saw it as a major wedge in the most recent U.K. election which gutted the Labour party. Both ostensibly “leftist” parties paid the price for abandoning their working-class constituencies by embracing the globalism touted by what’s often been termed the “professional managerial class” (PMC).

It should also be noted that recessions generally take a decade to shake out “naturally” that is, without the appropriate Keynesian counter-stimulus. Since the meltdown began in 2008; 2018 would be when we would expect the economy to start recovering in earnest, and this is pretty much what occurred. Again, unfortunately this occurred when Trump was in office. Of course, he’ll tout his tax cuts, but there is zero evidence that this has had any effect besides enriching the donor class. The quality of the new jobs is another matter as well, but that’s for another time.

So natural economic cycles have joined with demographics in the U.S. to encourage a relatively favorable economy for average people, at least for now. Trump will run out in front of the parade and claim he is leading it. The challenge for the rest of us it to ensure that the means of preventing rising wages and worker empowerment employed by corporations will not be effective. That will give us some ability to make things better in the future.

Incidentally, the population rate in the U.S. continues to decline, most likely because the demise of the middle class: US has slowest population growth rate in a century as births decline (The Guardian)

The Legal Nature of Money

Last time we looked at the Book The Code of Capital. The big idea of that book is that what constitutes capital – wealth generating assets – is the way they are encoded by laws. Law is what flips and asset from just another idea or piece of paper into something you can make money off of. And now theoretically anything can be coded as capital – even one’s own labor.

But law is intimately involved in more than just capital. It’s also behind what constitutes money.

We think of money as some neutral thing. But underneath it lies the same system of laws and regulations that creates capital. Certain types of money take precedence over others. Certain types of money have a higher claim on real resources, and those claims are determined by the state via law.

I’ve read about that idea before, but it was reinforced by this podcast with Rohan Grey, an attorney originally from Australia who writes about the money system. Here his is on the essential legal nature of how we order and design our economy and economic transactions:

[10:01] Rohan Grey: “I sometimes think of the scene in The Matrix where he’s kind of looking at everything and [seeing] the the green lines of code [behind everything].”

“Not that I would recommend anybody go to law school, but one of the things that is good about going to law school is that it trains you to see the legal ‘code’ behind almost every issue.”

“You know, you’re walking down the street and you see something, and go, ‘wow, that’s a lawsuit waiting to happen.’ Or you see someone putting up electrical wires, and you think, ‘I wonder who approved the local council ordinance for that to happen this way,’ or something.”

“So there’s just so many different things where, to borrow a line from the poet Rilke, ‘Don’t be confused by the surfaces; in the depths, everything is law.’

And so when you think about what money is, there’s a lot of times where people get hung up on either the physicality of it–whether it’s paper, or a coin, or a blip on a computer screen. They think money is the thing that they can point to, or the thing that they can hold.”

“There are other people who think that, very crudely speaking, money is what money does. If something is a store of value; if something is a medium of exchange, it is money.”

“Whereas, I think what we would say is that money is first and foremost a *relationship*. It’s a statement of social relations between people. And those social relations are structured by law and legal dynamics.”

“To give this an example or analogy, when people talk about what property is–property isn’t the thing…If I had a house, that wouldn’t be my property. My property would be the legal title to the house. And that wouldn’t mean that I suddenly owned the house. It would mean that I had a set of legal rights, and legal claims, against other people.”

“So when we talk about the property right to a house, the first thing that comes to your mind is a house. What we’re really thinking about is the relationship between me, and everyone else in the world, with respect to the house. It’s that web of invisible filaments between me and the state, between me and you, between me and other people who inhabit the house. That web is what the property right is, not the house itself.”

“So, to take that idea to money, it doesn’t matter whether we’re taking about a coin, or a paper note, or an account entry on a balance sheet, or a computer blip on a screen. The essence of money is the legal relationships that are structured between me and other people with respect to some sort of instrument, or some sort of monetary value.”

“And that relationship can be structured in different ways. It can be a form of private credit. So if I ‘owe you one,’ in the kind of broad favor sense, that might not be money. But if I owe you *one dollar*, and you know you can take me to court over that, and then you can take that IOU that I have for you…and give it to somebody else, and that person can take me to court, than that might be money. So something that started off as a sort of personal, informal favor, can become money once it gains certain legal properties.”

“Another kind of money–or the kind of money that the MMT story starts with and thinks is the most central to modern societies where most relationships go beyond the people that you know by name…the dominant form of money is the money that the state issues and says, ‘we will accept this for any legal debt that you owe to us, or to other people.'”

“So the way that MMT boils that down for the average person, is to say, ‘taxes drive the value of government money.’ Out of all the kinds of money that could be out there; out of all the kind of private credit relationships…the most important is the one that the state says will be acceptable for its own IOUs–its own debts to itself: taxes, court judgements, criminal fees and fines, [penalties]–that kind of money has the most wide acceptability because everybody knows that at some point they might incur legal damages. They might be sued. They might have to pay taxes. They might have to pay some sort of fee or fine. And if *they* don’t have to pay, someone else is going to have to pay, which means that if they accumulate some money, at the very least they’re going to be able to offload it to somebody else who needs it.”

…There’s only two things in life that are certain: death and legal liability risk. Even if you think you’re off-grid, even if you’re living in the Canadian wilderness and hunting bison with a bow and arrow…somebody could come along and get in an altercation with you, and the next thing you know you’re getting a court summons because they’ve sued you for hurting them…So it’s almost impossible to image a world where you’re not at risk. Even if you don’t have an *actual* bill from the government due tomorrow, you’re at risk of facing a bill from the government, even if you don’t have to pay taxes.
So that idea that at some point you might find the need to pay some sort of legally-denominated debt means that you–and anybody who is in a similar postion–is going to want to make sure you have access to some of the money that can pay that debt.

Which means that the best way to think about that money…is that it’s a tax credit, or that its a legal credit. And therefore, any instrument–whether it’s virtual or physical–that legally is recognized as being a tax credit, is going to have some degree of money[ness].

In Rohan’s telling, rather than money in the abstract, the fundamental social nature of money is taken into consideration. This is eliminated in standard economics curricula, which assumes everyone to be atomized strangers to everyone else, with no prior dealings.

We saw that even with “primitive money.” Earlier we looked at the essay “Primitive Money” by George Dalton. There we saw that “primitive” money isn’t used so much as a means of exchange for settling spot transactions between strangers, as it is in our culture. Rather, money is used as a means to discharge social obligations between people in a society.

Primitive money performs some of the functions of our own money, but rarely all; the conditions under which supplies are forthcoming are usually different; primitive money is used in some ways ours is not; our money is impersonal and commercial, while primitive money frequently has pedigree and personality, sacred uses, or moral and emotional connotations. Our governmental authorities control the quantity of money, but rarely is this so in primitive economies.

There are a couple of reasons why this is so. For one, there are very few “strangers” in traditional societies. For another, markets are not very important to society. They are tangential places of exchange, but they don’t order social relations, nor are hypothetically “self-adjusting” markets the sole means of resource distribution.

In our society, our social relationships tend to be structured primarily by money transactions in markets. There are exceptions of course—we still have families, after all. We can think of citizenship as another way to structure social relations between people.

But in traditional societies, social relationships are not structured around money. They are structured by other things—usually kinship. Money is simply one of the means of discharging one’s social obligations.

Some common social obligations are weddings and funerals. Bridewealth and dowries are a couple of examples. But delict and crime is another example, and one which which illustrates the social nature of money. In these cases, what constitutes payment will be determined by the authorities, and how much is required for the settlement of various offenses will also be determined by the relevant authorities. Ancient legal codes had a schedule of payments from one group to another based on the offense committed.

Relating to Rohan Grey’s argument above that the necessity of having a means of settlement with the authorities establishes the type of money that is most in demand, in many cultures what constitutes the acceptable means of settlement becomes the first type of money. In some cultures this is cattle; in others it might be shells, or metal coins, or whatever. Things than become priced in whatever that is, and a range of equivalencies are created (5 goats = 1 cow, etc.).

We’ve just abstracted so much that we’ve lost sight of this relationship.

If any means of settlement between two people or groups of people constitutes money, than we have an awful lot of different types of money. How do we differentiate them? The following are taken from a paper by Stephanie Bell entitled “The Hierarchy of Money.

In [G. F.] Knapp’s treatment, all money represents a Chartal means of payment. That is, all money is a ‘ticket’ or ‘pay-token’, which gains validity by proclamation that it will be accepted as a means of payment. These ‘tickets’ or ‘tokens’ which individuals/institutions have proclaimed acceptable as a means of payment do not become money until they have been accepted by another individual/institution.

Going back to Keynes, then, a great number of ‘things’ will answer to the ‘description’ or ‘title’ of money. That is, every plane ticket, pre-paid phone card, movie ticket, subway token, etc. is a form of Chartal money. It will, therefore, be useful to narrow our focus and to proceed with a simplified discussion of ‘the hierarchy’.

This is where the concept of a hierarchy of money comes in. And that hierarchy is once again determined by laws and legal institutions.

..a money’s place within the hierarchy depends on the degree to which it is accepted by society…

…the ‘hierarchy of money’ can be thought of as a multi-tiered pyramid where the tiers represent promises with differing degrees of acceptability. At the apex is the most acceptable or ‘ultimate’ promise. But if all promises are denominated in the same unit of account, why are some deemed more socially acceptable than others? Whose promises will be the most acceptable? And why would anyone agree to hold the relatively less acceptable promises?

The paper than goes on the list the numerous relationships structured by debt, and where they sit on the tier of money. The bottom tier consists of the debts of firms and households. The top tier consists of the debts owed to the state. The reason why the state’s debts rank higher than others is because the means of settlement with the state do not have to be converted into anything else in order to be valid:

To get business and household debts accepted, they might be made convertible into the debt of someone higher in the pyramid and may also require interest payments to compensate for the risk associated with holding less liquid assets…Unlike households and firms, state promises and certain bank promises would be accepted even if they were not convertible into anything else…Likewise, the state’s promises do not depend on convertibility into anything else…Recall that As the ‘decisive’ money of the system, both the state’s promises and banks’ promises rank high among the monies of the hierarchy…the legal obligation to pay taxes and the state’s proclamation that it will accept its own currency at state pay-offices elevate the state’s liabilities to the top of the pyramid, rendering them the promises with the highest degree of acceptability.

It concludes:

In short, not all money is created equal. Although the government, banks, firms and households can create money denominated in the social unit of account, these monies are not considered equally acceptable. Only the state, through its power to make and enforce tax laws, can issue promises that its constituents must accept if they are to avoid penalties. The general acceptability of both state and bank money derives from their usefulness in settling tax and other liabilities to the state.

What makes the capitalist system unique is that the debts between individuals can be monetized—that is converted into the state’s ultimate means of settlement, thus expanding the money supply. Again, this is entirely a creature of law. As Pistor pointed out, the state’s money unit can be used to structure horizontal relationships between individuals, and not just vertical relationships between the citizens and the state:

The test of ‘moneyness’ depends on the satisfaction of both of two conditions. First, the claim or credit is denominated in an abstract money of account. Monetary space is a sovereign space in which economic transactions (debts and prices) are denominated in a money of account. Second, the degree of moneyness is determined by the position of the claim or credit in the hierarchy of acceptability. Money is that which constitutes the means of final payment throughout the entire space defined by the money of account. Pigou’s ‘money’ was ‘proper’ not simply because it was backed by gold, but because the state pronounced the abstract money of account and established its exchange rate with gold.

A further important consideration is the process by which money is produced. Credit relations between members of a giro for the book transfer and settlement of debt were, as Innes observed, extensively used as early as Babylonian banking. However, these credit relations did not involve the creation of new money. In contrast, the capitalist monetary system’s distinctiveness is that it contains a social mechanism by which privately contracted credit relations are routinely ‘monetised’ by the linkages between the state and its creditors, the central bank, and the banking system.

Capitalist ‘credit money’ was the result of the hybridisation of the private mercantile credit instruments (‘near money’ in today’s lexicon) with the sovereign’s coinage, or public credits. The essential element is the construction of myriad private credit relations into a hierarchy of payments headed by the central or public bank which enables lending to create new deposits of ‘money’ – that is the socially valid abstract value that constitutes the means of final payment.

Credit and State Theories of Money by L. Randall Wray et. al., pp. 214-215

This is actually quite important in understanding how money not just as an abstract thing, but a way of social ordering created and reinforced by the state. Thus, you cannot have a market economy without a very specific set of laws and legal institutions established by states. And since the state is intimately involved, it makes no sense to argue that the state should somehow “get out of the way” of the market relations it established in the first place through laws, as libertarians argue for.